This is G o o g l e's cache of http://sixteenvolts.blogspot.com/2006/04/youre-always-thinking-about-money.html as retrieved on 13 Sep 2006 03:12:35 GMT.
G o o g l e's cache is the snapshot that we took of the page as we crawled the web.
The page may have changed since that time. Click here for the current page without highlighting.
This cached page may reference images which are no longer available. Click here for the cached text only.
To link to or bookmark this page, use the following url: http://www.google.com/search?q=cache:rakH0hkEWUQJ:sixteenvolts.blogspot.com/2006/04/youre-always-thinking-about-money.html+site:sixteenvolts.blogspot.com&hl=en&ct=clnk&cd=414


Google is neither affiliated with the authors of this page nor responsible for its content.

Send As SMS

« Home | Libraries make good sense » | For your grownup tastes » | Vice city » | Hobgoblin or Demogoblin? » | For he is an Englishman » | Eliminate some unnecessary redundancy » | Don't go there » | Confusion never stops » | Procrastination » | Honey, I picked up our new baby today »

You're always thinking about money instead of real people, man

A while back, I noticed that the Finnish MP Jyrki Kasvi hypothesized in his blog that perhaps the main reason why housing is so expensive in Finland is that the politicians who control zoning and other relevant issues are worried about the prices of the houses and investment apartments that they own. No shit, Sherlock. The motives of the BANANA crowd are not exactly difficult to comprehend when you think about them a little. People respond to incentives, as somebody once aptly put it. I am so happy that I get to live in an area that responds to masses of new people moving in the city by allowing more housing to be constructed for them. Imagine that.

It is good to occasionally remind ourselves about the limitless economic stupidity of the majority of people. For example, let us take a look at some of the comments in the post "Rent-Stabilized Rents Look Like They'll Go Up" at Gothamist, about rent control in New York. Just like every other socialist subsidy, rent control is great if you are the one who is getting the subsidy, but it sucks eggs for everybody else who have to pay for your subsidy in one form or another, since there is no free lunch. Behold the logic of some people who personally benefit from rent control:

Half the city would empty out if rent stabilization were ended. $1500-$2000 rents for one bedroom apts would be the norm, even in Flushing. I can't afford that, and I don't want to double or triple up.
for people who have lived in new york since before the 80's, rent stabilization is the only way that they are able to afford new york without living in a shelter.
My rent-stablized apartment is renting for less than the legally-allowable rent, so it's not hurting anybody, but it is a nice safety net for long-term residents, as someone said. It's OK to advocate for market rents when you're just parachuting in for a few years and then will be on your way back to the suburbs.
Why is rent stabilization dumb? It just is a safe guard against getting forced out of an apartment at the end of the lease. Otherwise he/she could raise it by any amount.

I sure would be interested in hearing what some landlord who is forced to rent out a place for $500 a month even though it would bring in $3000 in the free market has to say about the fact that he is forced to subsidize somebody $2500 each month. Also as expected, not one of these people even tries to come up with an explanation why they deserve to mooch off their landlords and stay in their rent-controlled apartments, but other people don't have the same right. Why does one person deserve to rent some apartment more than some other person who would be willing to pay more for it? What exactly makes this first person so special? Because we know the first person and hear his pitiful pleas how he doesn't want to "double or triple up", but not the second faceless person who then has to do exactly that?

Lots more people would like to live in New York than there are apartments, so the system must somehow "choose" who gets to live there. So why not choose those who are willing to pay for it? It's not like the landlords would keep their apartments empty, and the free market would set the rents on a level in which all apartments find a tenant. And you know, I must have missed it when somebody proved that living in a big expensive city is some kind of a unalienable basic human right that everybody inherently has: could somebody point me to the right direction to find this convincing argument? I would also wonder how smart it is for the future of the city to drive away the productive middle class to the suburbs so that you can provide cheap apartments to the poor and the underclass, as suggested in "Squeeze on tenants is bad for all", but I guess I that would make me a cold and evil reactionary. But hey, once the firemen and nurses and teachers can no longer afford to live in the city, perhaps somebody could wave his magic wand and build them special pixie dust magic apartments that are just as good and well-equipped as other apartments but whose rent is much lower.

Fortunately, Toronto no longer has the folly of rent control, even though the usual leftist idiots would apparently like it back. For more idiocy, see the page "Rent Controls in Ontario" that must be some kind of parody with the "myths" that it corrects. My favourite myth was clearly

Myth: Vacancy Decontrol doesn't hurt because it doesn't affect tenants who remain in their apartments.

Fact: It means many people can't afford to move, whether that move is to be closer to a job, or because of a breakup of a relationship, or to get a larger apartment because of the birth of a child, or to move out of one's parent's home.

To counter this idiocy, one of the commenters at Gothamist who wrote that

In my building on the Lower East Side, my landlord accidentally mailed out a list of what every tenant paid for three of their buildings. Needless to say I was shocked--I found that my neighbor who is a vocal advocate for tenants rights has a huge three bedroom apartment for $800, while I squeeze into a tiny converted 1 bedroom (or 2 bedroom as they call it) with my roommate for double that amount.

also linked to the excellent article "How Rent Control Drives Out Affordable Housing", which doesn't really contain anything that should be news to anybody with common sense, but sums up the idiocy of rent control quite nicely. Note especially the sections "Excluding Outsiders" and "Generational Subsidies". The latter section reminds me of the way the Student Unions in Finland proclaim that they provide inexpensive apartments for students. They just forget to mention that there are long queues to these apartments so that it takes years of waiting to get into them, and of course those students who get them keep living in them as long as they can, rather than pay higher rents in the free market. Since university studies are free in Finland, many students simply choose not to graduate but keep working and nominally sign up as students each year to maintain their student status forever and enjoy the subsidies.

9 comments

The most lucrative subsidies available to students in Finland are by far the train and bus tickets, which you get for half the price.

I would remove all student subsidies, since graduating in many cases actually decreases your disposable income, as a lot of stuff becomes much more expensive, and you don't get an immediate raise.

Nowadays TOAS (Tampere Student Housing Foundation) is trying to do something for nominal students. You have to prove that you have a right for a student apartment. I don't know if the system works or not, but at least living in TOAS apartment without really studying is not as simple as it used to be.

In Jyväskylä, the rent per square meter in student housing foundation's apartments seems to be actually higher than in the free market. The foundation has other strengths: simple and somewhat fair application process, shared apartments and a fixed internet connection in all apartments.

Any and all such control mechanisms only decrease the incentives towards graduating.

To get subsidies for travel in Helsinki after you are 30, you need "myönteinen opintotukipäätös", but before that you can take all subsidies that you want. I know one "computer scientist" who has never taken one course and actually has a well paid job. He just uses the system to get cheaper traver and postpone going to the army.

"And you know, I must have missed it when somebody proved that living in a big expensive city is some kind of a unalienable basic human right that everybody inherently has: could somebody point me to the right direction to find this convincing argument?"

This is quite interesting, coming from you, especially since a couple of days ago you clearly expressed that you don't consider living out in the middle of nowhere an unalienable basic human right, either. Well, of course neither living in the city nor living in the middle of nowhere nor any compromise solution between the two is an unalienable human right as such, but one does have to live somewhere.

BTW, too bad you did not get to watch when rent control shit hit the fan in Cambridge, MA in early nineties, you would have been very amused. My favorite was some poor bugger who was not allowed by zoning laws to have more than n units in his building, but also not allowed by rent control laws to have less than m units, either, where n was smaller than m. This was not an uncommon problem, but this particular guy was denounced by his rent-control tenants who just happened to be lawyers. Don't know what happened to him in the end.

Vera: This is quite interesting, coming from you, especially since a couple of days ago you clearly expressed that you don't consider living out in the middle of nowhere an unalienable basic human right, either.

I really don't see the problem, since I consider the individual right to live wherever you want to be the right to live wherever you can afford.

There is plenty of room between the downtown core and the exurbs, with options from a wide price range.

Mielestäni opiskelijajärjestöjen ei pitäisi tarjota ollenkaan yksiöitä. Jos kaikki alihintaiset kämpät kaikki ovat soluja, niihin on vähempää tunkua sitten kun on jo töissä. Normaali ihminen kyllästyy soluasumiseen viimeistään siinä vaiheessa kun pitäisi päästä avoliittoon. Vastaavasti alihintaisia pariasuntojakaan ei pitäisi olla.

Solu tai sitten vapaat markkinat olisivat minun vaihtoehtoni.

- Syltty

Ilkka; the problem is exactly that people have the right to live wherever they can afford, and yet some people cannot really afford to live anywhere. (And no, rent control is not a solution.)

I don't think you have to worry about tenant activists, just look at the history.

Whoa, did I find some interesting stuff on the Federation of Metro Toronto Tenants Associations page.

Look what I found on their FMTA sells out tenants article



This is a story about how in 1986, the Federation of Metro Tenants Associations demanded from the Ontario Liberal government of David Peterson that they must chose 9 people to represent all tenants in Ontario, and how those tenant representatives sold us all out to the Liberals.

Two of those tenant representatives are now the lead "tenant stakeholders" the Dalton McGuinty government is talking with, Dan McIntyre, head of the Federation of Metro Tenants Associations, and Kathy Laird, Legal Director of the Advocacy Centre for Tenants Ontario. We hope to get the complete list soon, and how many of them went to work for the government shortly after selling out the tenants of Ontario.

The Chair of that Committee, Leslie Robinson is who is quoted extensively in this article was put in charge of picking the Board of Directors and setting up the structure of the Advocacy Centre for Tenants Ontario, and Kathy Laird as Legal Director.

The results of the Residential Rent Regulation Act of 1986 that they supported, were the largest rent increases in Ontario history, with many buildings recieving one year rent increases of 20%, with some reaching 30 and 40% in a single year.



Rent Reform's Elusive Accord

Tenant reps are endorsing the Liberals' new rent review law but the associations they hail from want nothng to do with it.

Now, December 11-17, 1986
by Jane Story


A year ago, housing minister Alvin Curling, formed an advisory committe made up of nine landlord and nine tenant representatives. After months of negotiations, an agreement was reached by both sides and the committee's recommendations were incorporated into a new version of the Residential Rent Regulation act, now Bill 51, passed by the legislature yesterday (Wednesday).

It's obvious that such consensus is political manna for a party that hopes to woo both financially powerful owners and vote-heavy renters. Curling calls it an "historic agreement." But Curling's political gain may be at the tenant movement's expense. It looks like the historic divide between landlord and tenant has shifted bearings for the moment into a rift between tenant organizations which have denounced the bill and some tenant organizers who have given their support.

Bill 51 replaces rent review legislation that limits landlords to annual rent hikes of 4 per cent. The previous legislation had long been considered unsatisfactory, both by tenants — because so many buildings were exempted — and by landlords and the construction industry who say the impairment of profit crushed the incentive to build new rental housing in a market that is increasingly desperate for it.

The most obvious change in the new legislation is the replacement of the flat 4 per cent ceiling with a complex formula that takes each landlord's costs into consideration. Curling calls it "the most responsive, constructive and sensitive system of rent review in North America." But Bill 51 is so complex that no one can confidently predict its exact impact. What is certain is that it will have a far reaching effect on all the basic housing issues — inclucing new building construction, the retention of existing rental housing, building maintenance and rental costs.

Not surprisingly, part of the battle centers around differing interpretations of the hypothetical impact of the new regulations. But the debate also touches on the deeper problem of devising strategy in a new political context. After 42 years of Tory closed-door politics, the new minority government's markedly consultative approach has raised new issues for grassroots organizing efforts. The current political scene makes concessions possible which were all but unattainable in the past, though it's clear that the Liberals will never stray too far from the business interests to which they are committed. The tenant movement is being forced to confront just where to draw the line between compromise and cooptation.

To both the Tories and the NDP, the minister pitched his bill as a landlord-tenant truce, and he warned the opposition against any changes that would disturb the delicate balance of interest that has been struck.

The NDP was unconvinced. Housing critic David Reville, the Riverdale MPP, proposed 60 amendments to the legislation and refutes the government's claim that a settlement between landlords and tenants has been reached.



Never consulted
"Basically, the people on the rent review advisory committee were appointed by the government. It is an agreement between nine tenant representatives and nine landlord representatives, but there is a bit of fast footwork in the terms of the description of these people as representatives," he says.

This sentiment is echoed by Bart Poesiat, a staffer at Parkdale Community Legal Clinic — long a leader in the area of tenant rights — though the chairperson of Curling's committee is Mary Hogan, who was the director of the Parkdale Community Legal Clinic when she agreed to sign on.

"The Parkdale Tenants' Association ws never consulted and never knew anything about the committee or even that the committee was being formed," says Poesiat.

"When the bill first came out, the Parkdale Tenants' Association called a meeting and a lot of tenants came out and a lot of questions were asked. It was obvious that the bill was taking money out of the pockets of tenants and transferring it into the pockets of landlords with the hope that they would then start building new housing."

It is certainly the government's contention that Bill 51 will "set the stage for a rebirth of investor interest in rental housing." But even Leslie Robinson, who sat on the tenants' side of the advisory committee, undercuts these expectations. If any new rental housing is created, she sees it happeing at the high end of the market, unaffordable for many tenants.

So why did Robinson, a respected tenant advocate and coordinator of the Federation of Metro Tenants' Associations for 12 years, agree to collaborate?

Robinson maintains that along with all the other tenant representatives, she was nominated by the federation, although it was understood that she would not be representing the federation or binding it to any accord.

The federation has since been very critical of the legislation and last month rallied tenants to protest its ascent. In a brief submitted to the legislative committee debating the bill, the federation contended that the new rent reforms will not end "the gouging that forces tenants to subsidize speculators" and will ultimately "make the rich richer and the poor poorer."

Robinson defends her position on the advisory committee, which she still holds.

"The report that I signed was a recommendation based on what I thought we could get out of the Liberals, not what I want to see ultimately. I can't say this is the best policy in the world or even that this is a fairly good policy, but given what the Liberal government was intending to do, this is what I think is the best we could get.

"I believed, and I still do, that we got more reforms and a better housing policy by participating in the process and signing the report than we would have got if we had pursued lobbying."

Included in Robinson's inventory of achievements is a commitment from the minister to build 3,000 non-profit housing units, a recommendation for security of tenure for roomers and boards, and Bill 11, passed last summer. Robinson argues that Bill 11, which prevents the demolition of existing housng or its conversion to high-priced condominiusm, would never have gone through if tenant reps on the advisory committee had not made support for Bill 51 conditional on the passing of Bill 11.

Robinson estimates that more than 10,000 units were saved in metro. Her critic scoff. They see Bill 11, effetive for only two years, as a weak law, already assured by the Liberal-NDP accord, and not worth the tradeoff.

Tenant groups are particularly opposed to the government's calculated rent guideline, a complex formula equalling 2 per cent plus two-thirds of a typical landlord's operating costs, which on average will increase rents by 5.2 per cent next year. Rents could go much higher since no ceiling has been put on increases.



More reforms
This arrangement is supposed to ensure good maintenance and tenant protection during periods of high inflation. But the metro tenants federation is skeptical. "Once all the weighing and averaging is over," the federation says, "the formula boils down to a very simple and unfair conclusion: pay the landlord for his cost increases and then pay 2 per cent of your rent more each year."

Robinson also sees the regulation as a concession to landlords that was necessary even though it weakens the bill from the tenant point of view.

"It was a concession to landlords who were saying, `If you want us to improve the maintenance, we have to increase our operating costs.' So we gave them the money but we didn't make any requirement for them to improve the maintenance. I expect some responsible landlords will improve their maintenance but irresponsible landlords will put that money in their pockets.



Bill's cost
"One per cent is to cover capital expenses and financial cost increases that the landlord would have endured rather than going to rent review. The extra one per cent is more profit for landlord. In my mind, it is the cost of Bill 11."

"In the last three or four years, I was hearing more tenants complain to me about the lack of supply and poor maintenance and the loss of housing through demolition than I was hearing tenants tell me the rent review guidelines are too high. I don't hear very many tenants say, `I can't pay an extra one per cent.' I hear a lot of people say, `I have no where to go and my buidlng is being torn down.'"

However, there are concerns with even modest rent increase because of the decline in the relative income of tenants. The federation points out that in 1983, tenants' incomes were more than 22 per cent lower than in 1971. According to Statistics Canada, almost one-fifth of tenants are already paying 40 per cent or more of their incomes in rent, while nearly one-third pay more than 30 per cent. The NDP estimates that tenants will have to fork up an extra $1.4 billion in rent over the next five years as a result of the new guidelines.

Another bone of contention for tenant groups is the new rent registry. "The problem with the rent registry is that it starts now," says Poesiat. "What we've always argued is that it should register rents going back to 1976, when rent review came into place. (Under the bill) if a tenant does prove that his rents are illegal and, say he has been paying rents for five years, he can only collect the excesd rents he has been paying since August 1985. This is like pardoning the landlord for committing crimes. It's an amnesty for landlords.



Landlord pardon
The advisory committee also recommended that registered rents be deemed legal if a landlord, who has not previously gone to rent review for an increase, can prove that if he had, the legal rent would now be close to what he is charging. This, too, amounts to a pardon, the committee admits.

The amnesty was a major demand of the landlords, says Robinson. "In deciding to give in to that demand, it seems that in making a tradeoff what we were talking about were lump sums of money on a fairly random basis. It's all dealing in the past, it's not going to bring rents down."

Extending rent control to properties built since 1975 is providing universal protection for tenants, the government claims. But critics don't consider this the case, since the registry exempts rooming and boarding housing, ostensibly because of administrative difficulties.

But the most controversial aspect of the new law is one which allows landlords an additional 2 per cent increase if their rates of return are less than 10 per cent or if the rent charged is deemed chronically depressed — more than 20 per cent below the going rate.

Robinson does not feel accountable for this provision, as it is the one aspect of the new law which the advisory committee did not recommend. The tenant representatives recognize that this provision to raise the lowest rent to market levels will erode affordable housing, particularly in Parkdale. Landlords did not recommend this provision either. They wanted more.

Though these disadvantaged landlords may prove difficult to distinguish, their tenants are more easily identified. A study commissioned by the advisory committee showed that over 40 per cent of tenants being charged depressed rents are paying 25 per cent or more of their incomes in rent. One quarter of these tenants are either retired or out of work. Critics predict hardship relief for landlords will mean economic eviction for tenants.

A scathing review of Bill 51 was prepared by the Tenant Umbrella Group, a committee of legal workers and lawyers which was formed to represent their clients at the hearings of the now defunct Thom Commission, the Conservative inquiry into rent review reforms."

The umbrella group challenges the Liberals' definition of chronically depressed rents, and questions the premise that market rents are desirable. They argue that fixing the price of accommodation at market levels assumes that market forces are in place — which they are not, as the present low vacancy rates indicate. They fear increase will bring affordable rents up to currenly illegal levels.



Scathing review
The relief clause also allows landlords to immediately raise their rents to the market rate if the unit becomes vacant or the tenant agrees to the increase. Reville foresees huge possibilities for coercion here.

"I see landlords forcing tenants to sign these agreements or getting them out just so they can fast track their units." Reville tried to have this section deleted.

Another consideration for the economic well-being of the landlrods is the clause to cover financial loss. The bill's critics say loss is incurred when properties are turned over for a fast buck — like the 1982 Cadillac Fairview deal. After that scam, a cap of 5 per cent spread over five years was put on claims for financial loss. Critics are concerned the erosion of this protection detected in Bill 51 will encourage speculation and building flips.

Robinson feels tenants should not have to pay for a landlord's financial losses, and says the tenant reps on the committee tried in vain to wipe out this provision.



One mistake
"We kept the 5 per cent but we didn't keep the five-year basis. In my mind, this is the one mistake we made and I think it will encourage the sale of more buildings. If there is one thing I wish the legislation would change, it is that."

Landlords have their reservations too about Bill 51, but say its is a step towards eliminating rent controls altogether.

Meanwhile, the advisory committee continues to meet, although at least three tenant representatives have since resigned from the tenant organizations they were initially affiliated with.

"By the time I quit (the federation)," says Robinson, "I was feeling I just couldn't keep wearing two hats. I realized what the differnece was. If you are an advisor to the minister, that's one thing and if you're representing tenants and saying, `This is the position tenants take,' that's another thing. I couldn't keep publicly clear what hat I was wearing."

"The question is, how is there going to be an assurance that the assigned representatives actually represent tenants. I think we represented them. I don't think we were representing any other interests, but if the advisory committee is going to continue, we have to make sure that there be more work done connecting the committee to tenant groups."

It may not be too late. The advisory committee could set about reforming the Landlord and Tenant Act next.

Post a Comment

Links to this post

Create a Link

Contact

ilkka.kokkarinen@gmail.com

Buttons

Site Meter
Subscribe to this blog's feed
[What is this?]